From
Send to

[Andrew Sheng] Why do nations fail or succeed?

Aug. 26, 2013 - 20:18 By Yu Kun-ha
August is the holiday month ― the time when we pause to take stock of a hectic first half year, and wonder what lies ahead.

Nestled in the hills of northern Laos, the ancient city of Luang Prabang sits around a bend in the river Mekong, isolated for centuries and renowned today as a city of 15th century Buddhist temples, protected as a UNESCO Heritage site. It was a good place to catching up on one’s history to try to comprehend the uncertain future. 

The recent best-seller by MIT economics professor Daron Acemoglu and Harvard political scientist James Robinson: “Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity and Poverty” (Penguin 2012) argued that national failures were all due to man-made factors, more specifically, how political institutions became extractive, rather than inclusive.

Acemoglu and Robinson are provocative because they stir up the debate on why Latin American economies never quite made it, even though they were resource rich. They did not succeed despite huge wealth because their political institutions remained extractive, meaning a few hundred families or elite essentially controlled the key resources of the continent for their own benefit. Another obvious example is the difference between North Korea, one of the poorest countries around, and South Korea, an innovative and dynamic economy capable of challenging the best of the West, by learning from the West.

The Acemoglu and Robinson book touches on a raw nerve because many in the West are unsure whether they will continue to be dominant in the years to come. They argue that China will sooner or later stop growing because the institutions there are becoming extractive. But as one review argued, it cannot be ruled out that Chinese institutions would evolve into inclusive systems. After all, China could not have succeeded without being inclusive ― taking more than half a billion out of poverty.

In the same genre, Stanford professor of classics and history, Ian Morris’s 2011 book, “Why the West Rules ― For Now: The Patterns of History and What They reveal about the Future,” takes also the grand sweep, arguing not only about the factors of biology and sociology, but also about geography. So instead of Acemoglu and Robinson’s dictum, “institutions, institutions and institutions,” Morris considers that it is more about “location, location, location.” He argues that biology and sociology explain the similaries in development between the East and West, but “it is geography that explains why the West rules.”

This view concurs with Asian historian Wang Gung-wu’s perceptive insight that the West developed maritime and today air and cyberspace technology and power, whereas China remains essentially a continental or land-based power. Geography does shape behavior and perception.

Personally, I am less persuaded by what caused nations to fail than what caused them to succeed, and not just succeed for a few decades, but remain relevant for centuries.

Most people forget that the first modern economy in the world was not Portugal or Spain, or England, but Holland. Even though the Portuguese and Spaniards opened up the maritime routes to America and the Spice Islands, they remained feudal powers that never evolved the institutions to manage their colonies efficiently and professionally.

Last month in Amsterdam, I was given a copy of Marius van Nieuwkerk’s history of “Dutch Golden Glory: The Financial Power of the Netherlands through the Ages” (2006). This wonderful gem of a book, beautifully illustrated, attributed the rise of Holland to a conquest of man over water. As we all know, Holland has only a population of 16.6 million, in an area 20 percent larger than the island of Taiwan, ranked 17th in the world in terms of GDP, and 14th in terms of GDP per capita, at $46,100 just behind the U.S. ($50,000) and Japan ($46,700), but ahead of old rivals, the U.K. ($38,600).

Historically, because of constant flooding in its low-lying land, the Dutch learnt to work cooperatively to build dykes, through “poldering” ― constant irrigation, drainage and pumping of water. Thus, in their constant struggle against flooding and weather risks, the Dutch developed their infrastructure cooperatively, learning how to manage risks through precaution (high savings), consultation (constant feedback) and inspection (maintenance of strict standards). To do so, they built highly inclusive, flexible and innovative institutions that opened up to global trade.

Their constant struggle against water meant that the Dutch had superior shipbuilding technology, drawing on timber from the Baltic areas and arbitraging the trade with Northern Europe. By 1598, the Dutch had established the first Insurance Chamber, the largest trading company by 1602 (VOC), and forerunner of the first central bank, the Amsterdam Exchange Bank in 1609, Merchants Exchange 1611, and Grain Exchange in 1616.

The VOC, which had trading monopoly for the East Indies in the spice trade, was so profitable that between 1602-1796 the average dividend was 18.5 percent annually! Indeed, the Dutch were successful because they were not only good traders, but also insurers and bankers to the rest of Europe. One tends to forget that as late as 1750, 30 percent of the share capital of the Bank of England was owned by the Dutch.

What is remarkable about the Dutch model is not that it has not been taken over by other larger powers, but its sustainability and durability. The Dutch runs one of the largest pension funds in the world, and a recent study has shown that there are over 400 Dutch companies with over a century of history, including one that survived from 1530. It goes to show that a country may be small, but through thrift, hard-work, openness, and good governance, the country could succeed despite the odds.

There is much that the East has still to learn from the West. No history is a straight line, and there is nothing inevitable about success or failure. Whether it is Abenomics or Likenomics, the key to sustainable and inclusive growth is about strong social institutions with the right checks and balances. 

By Andrew Sheng

Andrew Sheng is president of the Fung Global Institute ― Ed.

(Asia News Network)